Showing all posts tagged #fed:


US FOMC Minutes digest: concerned about inflation; risk management was behind decision to raise rates

Posted on January 6th, 2016

Main takeaways:
  • Minutes confirmed risk management was key to the decision to increase rates (see US FOMC digest: risk management):
    • monetary policy has lags;
    • for FOMC members, an 'early' and gradual hike, therefore, reduces the risk "it might need to tighten policy abruptly" later on;
    • the asymmetric risks posed by rates still close to zero was dealt with by promising to keep a large balance sheet "until normalization" of interest rates is "well under way."
  • FOMC minutes stressed a couple of times the dichotomy between domestic and foreign developments:
    • participants took the view that domestic demand would only be partially offset by weakness in net exports, and
    • acknowledged downside risks from global and financial developments had receded.
  • Inflation outlook was debated at length by FOMC:
    • members noted the decline in oil prices "was likely to exert some additional transitory downward pressure on inflation in the near term.
    • members also noted that "some survey-based measures" of inflation expectations moved down, and several members expressed unease with that.
    • for some members, risks to their inflation forecasts remained considerable (further shocks to oil and commodities; a sustained rise in US dollar).
    • a couple worried global disinflationary forces could be more important than improving labor market for the inflation outlook.
    • some members said the decision to raise rates was a close call, given uncertainty about inflation dynamics.
  • Above mentioned concern with inflation was reflected in the statement saying that the Committee "would carefully monitor actual and expected progress toward its inflation goal."
  • However, the hurdle for inflation is not very tough -- underlying PCE momentum is running in the 1.2%-1.5% range, and the Fed central tendency forecasts for 2016 is 1.2%-1.7%.

US FOMC digest: risk management

Posted on December 17th, 2015

Main takeaways:
  • Dovish hike delivered; the gradual base case is 100bp/year, but market is not convinced; Fed emphasizes policy remains accommodative.
  • Key reason for moving (when inflation is still low): monetary policy has lags; a delay increases risk of abruptly tightening later.
  • Reference to actual inflation and that inflation expectations have to be well anchored probably helped to bring the doves on board.
  • However, the hurdle for inflation is not very demanding -- underlying PCE momentum is running in the 1.2%-1.5% range and the Fed central tendency forecasts for 2016 is 1.2%-1.7%.
  • Fed expects neutral fed funds (r*) to raise only gradually; markets, on the other hand, are betting on a secular stagnation type of story -- r* remains zero for the next two years and monetary policy stance remains even more accommodative than today.


FOMC
Comments
Policy decision
Raise the target range for the federal funds rate to 1/4 to 1/2 percent. Monetary policy remains accommodative.
Reinvestment policy will continue until "normalization of the level of the federal funds rate is well under way" -- this should "reduce the risk that fed funds rate might return to the effective lower bound in the event of future adverse shocks".
Why?
"Considerable progress that has been made toward restoring jobs, raising incomes, and easing the economic hardship of millions of Americans", and reflects "confidence that the economy will continue to strengthen". The recovery, however "is not yet complete": there's room for labor market to improve further and inflation continues to run below 2%. So why increase rates?
a) softness in inflation is due to transitory factors that should abate over time;
b) diminishing slack should put upward pressure on inflation as well;
c) it takes time for monetary policy actions to affect future economic outcomes;
d) a delay of normalization (for too long) increases risk of abruptly tightening policy at some point to avoid overshooting the goals.

Risks
Risks are balanced.
Policy outlook
In "determining the timing and size of future adjustments", FOMC "will carefully monitor actual and expected progress toward our inflation goal". Also, FOMC confidence in the inflation outlook rests importantly on its judgment that longer-run inflation expectations remain well anchored.
Normalization process likely to proceed gradually. This is consistent with the view that neutral nominal fed funds rate (r*) is currently low by historical standards.
FOMC expects that with "gradual adjustments in the stance of monetary policy" economic activity will continue to expand at a moderate pace and labor market indicators will continue to strenghten -- by how much? look at forecasts.

Discussion on equilibrium / neutral fed funds rate (r*)
The FOMC expects federal funds rate to remain, for some time, below levels that are consistent with its longer run assessment. The key rational behind this idea is that for that is the neutral rate (r*) is currently low and will only move gradually towards its long term level.

Why is r* low?
Because of the headwinds: tighter underwriting standards, limited access to credit, deleveraging, contractionary fiscal policy, weak growth abroad, significant appreciation of the dollar, slower productivity and labor force growth, elevated uncertainty about economic outlook.
These have declined noticeably over the past few years, but some have remained significant. As these abate, r* should gradually move higher over time -- this can be seen in the SEP.

How do you know for sure that r* is low?
One indication is that growth has been only moderate despite very low level of funds rate and the large balance sheet. Had r* been higher, economic expansion would have been much more rapid.

How low?
During the October FOMC meeting the staff briefed participants about the topic and the conclusion leaned towards:
  • r* was negative in the aftermath of the 2008-09 financial crisis and is currently close to zero.
  • Equilibrium level of r* would likely remain low relative to estimates before the financial crisis (due to productivity and demographic factors). This is reflected in SEP's forecast of 1.5% real rate in the long run (below the 2% used in the past).

According to the Taylor rule mentioned by Yellen (Yellen's preferred Taylor rule) on her remarks earlier this year (Normalizing Monetary Policy), even considering r*=0 (the green line in the chart below) the Fed would already be behind the schedule. An r*=0 (and current readings on PCE inflation and unemployment rate) would imply fed funds approximately 50bp higher -- this is why the Fed calls the monetary policy stance accommodative (below the neutral).

The fact that the slope of the 'dots' curve is higher than the green line reflects the idea of r* gradually moving higher over time. Market forecasts, on the other hand, are betting on a secular stagnation type of story -- r* remains zero for the next two years and monetary policy stance remains a bit more accommodative as it is today (a bit more than 50bp below the r*=0 line).


Emphasis on actual inflation
The newly introduced actual in the sentence "the Committee will carefully monitor actual and expected progress toward our inflation goal" was probably key to bring the doves on board (the other was the reference to the reinvestment policy, which would continue until "normalization of the level of the federal funds rate is well under way" -- this probably helped to please Brainard).

However, the Committee was smart enough to leave this comment flexible enough to avoid tyeing the Fed to a given path of inflation. Chair Yellen ably avoided giving any hard target when questioned by reporters. They avoided the historical mistake of the 6.5% unemployment target...

"Now, I've tried to explain in many of my -- and many of my colleagues have as well why we have reasonable confidence that inflation will move up over time, and the committee declared it had reasonable confidence. Nevertheless, that is a forecast. We really need to monitor over time actual inflation performance to make sure that it is conforming, it is evolving, in the manner that we expect. So it doesn't mean that we need to see inflation reach 2 percent before moving again, but we have expectations for how inflation will behave, and were we to find that the underlying theory is not bearing out, that it is not behaving in the manner that we expect, and that it doesn't look like the shortfall is transitory and disappearing with tighter labor markets, that would certainly give us pause. And we have indicated that we are reasonably close, not quite there, but reasonably close to achieving our maximum employment objective. But we have a significant shortfall on inflation. So we are calling attention to the importance of verifying that things evolve in line with our forecasts."

"I'm not going to give you a simple formula for what we need to see on the inflation front, in order to raise rates again. We will also be looking at the path of employment as well as the path for inflation. But if incoming data were, led us to call into question the inflation forecast that we have set out, and that could be a variety of different kinds of evidence, that would certainly give the committee pause. But I don't want to say there is a simple benchmark. The committee expects inflation over the next year at the median expectation is for inflation to be running about 1.6 percent. And both core and headline, so we do expects it to be moving up, but we don't expect it to reach 2 percent."

The chart below gives a good picture of recent inflation performance. Both headline and core inflation were increasing at the same pace (about 1.5%) from late 2011 to mid 2014, when oil prices were roughly flat. From October 2014 to January headline inflation dropped 0.8% (-3.4% annualized) reflecting the drop in energy prices, and has increased 1.1% until last October (about 1.4% annualized). This late rebound is headline prices is roughly in tandem with the pace of core inflation.

Core CPI inflation momentum is already running 2.4% (details here) but the gap with PCE inflation has opened and core PCE momentum is in the 1.2%-1.5% range. The Fed expects PCE inflation in the 1.2% to 1.7% range in 2016 (central tendency) so the bar is not very high.
However, further decline in oil prices and/or strengthening of the dollar could easily delay Fed action.


FOMC reference scenario
The table below is a reference to the FOMC base case, which is compatible with "gradual adjustments in the stance of monetary policy" -- i.e., 100bp/year.
The evolution of the actual economic variables and the evolution of Fed's forecasts will tell whether the economy is ahead or behind the base case.



Chart 1) Evolution of Fed forecasts for unemployment and inflation
Unemployment rate
PCE inflation



Chart 2) Dots and the implied Taylor rule

Taylor rule
Fed funds in 2015 below the r*=0 Taylor rule -- meaning monetary policy stance is accommodative
Dots for 2016 still imply a accommodative policy stance -- even assuming r* remains at zero!
Dots for 2017 moved down, suggesting the Fed sees headwinds taking longer to abate.



US financial conditions and commodity prices ahead of the historical FOMC tomorrow

Posted on December 15th, 2015

Main takeaways:
  • Commodities (including oil) breaking new lows.
  • Strong USD.
  • Equities off the highs with increasing vol.
  • Baa - Aaa spreads widening. High yield mkt close to panic.
  • But overall financial conditions are off the highs observed earlier in the year.

Charts

US trade-weighted dollar is higher than earlier in the year, when Fed warned about its negative consequences to the economy.

Oil prices are also at the lows.

Retail gasoline prices are close to the lows.

Commodity prices also at the lows.

US equities recovered part of its Aug/Sep losses, but face renewed uncertainty.

Equity vol is high again.


US 10y Treasuries

Baa spreads widened



Market-based inflation compensation sharply down, but this could just be oil prices

Financial conditions, as measured by GS, are tighter than in the last few years.

...but broadening the definition to include oil prices show a more benign picture

Financial conditions, as measured by the Chicago Fed, also show a tightening, but overall levels remain in the accommodative range

Adjusting for the business cycle, Chicago Fed index suggest that financial conditions moved to tight earlier in 2015 and are now back to easy.

Below, some additional financial conditions and financial stress indices

Longer history of financial conditions and the relevant episodes.



FOMC minutes: getting ready for a 'dovish hike'

Posted on November 18th, 2015

Minutes from the October meeting hint at an FOMC that is aiming at a dovish hike in December.

Dovish because: (a) it seems likely that they will emphasize the low equilibrium real rates as a reason for "keeping the target federal funds rate below the levels the Committee views as normal in the longer run" even after full employment and 2% inflation, and (b) it appears likely that a message will be sent that the Fed will not run out of ammunition and it would be ready to reverse course if economy unexpectedly weakens (perhaps "unconventional" policies will become "conventional"?).

The point (b) above is important because it might be what is needed for the 'doves' to be on board for voting for a hike next month.


Main takeaways from the Committee:
  • Decision to be on hold explained:
    • Almost all members agreed it was appropriate to wait for additional information to clarify whether the recent deceleration in the pace of progress in the labor market was transitory or reflected more persistent factors (note: the October report, released after the meeting, was probably enough to conclude deceleration was transitory).
    • Also, in the absence of greater confidence about the inflation outlook, it would be prudent to wait for additional information.
  • How much further progress in labor market is needed?
    • Members expressed a range of views regarding the extent of further progress in labor market indicators they would need to see to judge it appropriate to raise the target range for the fed funds in December.
  • How much progress toward 2 percent inflation?
    • The same bla bla that members anticipate inflation would gradually return to 2% over the medium term.
    • But minutes mentioned that most of the members were not yet sufficiently confident of that to begin increasing rates.
    • A couple of members expressed concern about the continued decline in market-based measures of inflation compensation. "Moreover, the risk was noted that downward pressures on inflation from the appreciation of the dollar could persist".
    • The October CPI report, however, has shown all the measures of core inflation rising (see http://bit.ly/USOctCPI).
  • Changes to postmeeting statement:
    • FOMC changed its near-term policy path from the assessment that would be needed to determine "how long to maintain the current target range" to what would be needed to determine "whether it would be appropriate to raise the target range at its next meeting".
    • The idea was to convey the information that rates would be increased IF: (a) unanticipated shocks do not adversely affect economic outlook, and (b) incoming data support expectation labor market will continue to improve and inflation will return to 2%.
    • So the goal was to leave policy options open for December; but a couple of members worried this could be signaling too strongly that rates would be increased in December.


Discussion on equilibrium real rates (r*)
  • The staff briefed the participants regarding the concept of an equilibrium real interest rate (r*).
  • Conclusions leaned towards:
    • r* was negative in the aftermath of the 2008-09 financial crisis and is currently close to zero.
    • Equilibrium level of r* would likely remain low relative to estimates before the financial crisis (due to productivity and demographic factors).
  • Policymakers made a number of observations:
    • actual levels of short-term real rate has been below r* (but not substantially below), consistently with estimates that r* is currently close to zero.
    • a number of participants expect r* to rise as the expansion continues (but probably only gradually).
    • r* will not go back to pre-crisis levels (this is why the dot for long run nominal fed funds has been falling in Fed's forecasts).
    • Lower r* imply rates will be closer to the ZLB --- and this "might increase the frequency of episodes in which policymakers would not be able to reduce the federal funds rate enough".
    • Therefore "some participants noted that it would be prudent to have additional policy tools that could be used in such situations".

According to the Taylor rule mentioned by Yellen on her remarks earlier this year, even considering r*=0 (the green line in the chart below) the Fed would already be behind the schedule. An r*=0 (and current readings on PCE inflation and unemployment rate) would imply fed funds at 0.75% in Sept/15 and 1% by December (based on Fed's forecasts).

This might be what Fischer had in mind when he mentioned last week that monetary policy has already responded to the dollar appreciation and foreign weakness "through deferring liftoff relative to what was expected".



Participants' Views:
  • There was a lot of talk about the labor market in the aftermath of a slowdown in job gains in August and September, and the discussion centered on whether it was temporary or more persistent. Hawks and doves made the usual arguments.
  • There was somewhat widespread concern with downside risks to inflation (mentioning market-based measures of inflation compensation).
  • Arguments against delaying increasing rates were presented: delay could increase uncertainty in financial markets, unduly magnify the importance of the beginning of policy normalization, increasing risk of a buildup of financial imbalances, decision to delay could be interpreted as signaling lack of confidence in the US economy, could erode FOMC credibility, progress should be measured in light of the cumulative gains without placing excessive weight on month-to-month changes in incoming data.
  • Arguments for delaying were also presented: downside risks to the outlook remained, concerns about loss of momentum in the economy, that inflation might fail to increase, uncertainty about whether growth was robust enough to withstand potential adverse shocks given limited ability of monetary policy to offset such shocks, concern that beginning of normalization might be associated with unwarranted tightening of financial conditions -- risk management considerations would call for caution, premature tightening might damage FOMC credibility to reach 2% inflation.
  • From the size of the previous two bullets, one may infer the arguments are balanced.
  • But the more important, perhaps, was that "several participants" think it would be prudent to consider options for providing additional policy accommodation if the economic outlook were to weaken and undermine progress in labor market conditions and reaching 2% inflation.


FOMC minutes: all we need is confidence...but we only get uncertainty

Posted on October 8th, 2015

Minutes confirmed my preliminary assessment after the statement and press conference: "The Fed has not materially changed the outlook, neither the balance of risks, but has acknowledged an increase in uncertainty. And if one is not willing to show this uncertainty in the forecasts, you show it by lowering the 'dots' when your forecast suggest otherwise, and sound dovish".

Main takeaways from September minutes:
  • Decision to be on hold explained:
    • All but one member agreed developments over the intermeeting period had not materially changed the outlook.
    • But, "in part because of risks to the outlook for economic activity and inflation" they decided it was prudent to wait for additional information to bolster their confidence on inflation returning to target.
  • Wait a minute: didn't they write that the balance of risks had remained unchanged?
  • But the minutes make it clear: The balance of risks has not changed. But the risk of risks has! (in other words, uncertainty) - This was the missing information in the statement and press conference...(see Frank Knight for the difference between risk and uncertainty).
  • Members agree that unemployment rate is at a level "quite close to" NAIRU.
  • Not quite there yet:
    • many members think labor market conditions met or would soon meet one of the Committee's criteria for liftoff.
    • but some members indicated confidence on returning inflation to target had not increased (because global economic and financial developments)
  • Most members need to see growth to "continue to expand at moderate rate" and labor market conditions to "improve further" for them to increase their confidence on inflation returning to target.
  • So when to move?
    • Many members expect conditions to be met later this year.
    • But several members were concerned about downside risks to growth and inflation.
    • A couple of members expressed unease with decline in market-based measures of inflation compensation. (Yellen seems to be one of them, based on her remarks in the Q&A)
  • Yellen seems to be on the very dovish side of the debate. And she's the boss.
  • Some of the comments that the September decision had been a 'close call' were not evident in the minutes. At least among voters (Williams included), all but Lacker easily agreed to wait for more information.
  • Meeting-by-meeting and data dependency continues to hold...


US FOMC: The headwinds keep blowing...

Posted on September 18th, 2015

Main takeaways:
  • The 25bp cut in the median 'dot' is not compatible with the change in forecasts.
  • This is happening since Sept/14. Blame it on the 'headwinds'.
  • Interestingly, the headwinds have consistently failed to affect Fed's forecasts. They only make their way to the underlying path of equilibrium real rates.



Despite FOMC's dovish statement and remarks, the forecasts for 2016 and 2017 have not changed materially:


Nevertheless, the 'dots' moved down by 25bp across the board. Is it compatible with the forecast revisions?

In order to check this, I have used Yellen's preferred Taylor rule -- the one she mentioned in her speech on Normalizing Monetary Policy.

The chart below plugs Fed forecasts into Yellen's Taylor rule for December 2015. It shows the implied path for interest rates assuming zero real rates (the solid light gray line) and assuming real rates at the long run value forecast by the Fed.

The lines with markers show the median and the trimmed average 'dots'. One can see that the Fed's median forecasts for interest rates at the end of 2015 have been consistent with negative real rates since mid-2013. The average in the period from Jun/13 to Jun/15 was -35bp and the most recent median dot is compatible with real rates at -65bp.


When looking at 2016 forecasts, the picture changes materially. The updated forecasts suggest nothing has materially changed in the Taylor rule range, however the median dot for December 2016 has consistently moved down since September/14. The most recent median dot is compatible with equilibrium real interest rates at -35bp.


The trend for 2017 is similar to 2016: the implied equilibrium real rate moved down by 100bp in the last year (but is currently compatible with equilibrium real rates at +50bp).


The bottom line is: no, the change in the 'dots' is not compatible with the change in forecasts (assuming the reaction function has not changed).

Therefore, the pattern of the last four FOMC dot-plots can only be compatible with the famous 'headwinds' (low oil and commodities, strong dollar, slower global growth) which, interestingly, have consistently failed to affect the forecasts. They only make their way to the underlying path of equilibrium real rates!

The chart below shows the implied Yellen Taylor rule assuming 1.5% real rate (red) and zero real rate (green). The blue dots are the median dot in the Fed's forecast and the chart shows also the fed fund futures the day before the meeting and as of September 18. Markets are skeptical the Fed will be able to follow its own plan (and markets have been right, so far).






US FOMC: Hinted at December liftoff, but within a very dovish framework

Posted on September 17th, 2015

Main takeaways:
  • FOMC hinted the most likely meeting for liftoff is December.
  • Yellen message was: FOMC has not "fundamentally altered its outlook", the risks remain balanced, but uncertainty increased; thus...
  • ...FOMC wants more evidence to bolster its confidence inflation will return to 2%.
  • However, the message was conveyed in a very dovish framework that sounded like a departure from the previous reaction function.

The FOMC surprised with a clear "dovish hold". The question is, why?

The quick answer comes straight into the statement:

"Recent global economic and financial developments may restrain economic activity somewhat and are likely to put further downward pressure on inflation in the near term."

A more explicit link from global developments to domestic developments is provided in Yellen's prepared remarks at the press conference:

"My colleagues and I continue to expect that the effects of these factors on inflation will be transitory. However, the recent additional decline in oil prices and the further appreciation of the dollar mean that it will take a bit more time for these effects to fully dissipate."

In another passage of her prepared remarks, Yellen explained what has made FOMC to change stance: equity prices, stronger dollar and spreads.

Developments since our July meeting, including the drop in equity prices [-5%], the further appreciation of the dollar [2%], and a widening in risk spreads [20bp], have tightened overall financial conditions to some extent. These developments may restrain US economic activity somewhat and are likely to put further downward pressure on inflation in the near term."
Note: the numbers in [ ] were not mentioned by Yellen.

So should we just focus on financial conditions? Not so fast... the Fed claims it does not target financial conditions... during Q&A Yellen stated:

"The Fed should not be responding to the ups and downs of the markets and it is certainly not our policy to do so. But when there are significant financial developments, it's incumbent on us to ask ourselves what is causing them ... And so they have concerned us in part because they take us to the global outlook and how that will affect us."

Ok. Now I got it. The FOMC has changed its global outlook and therefore its US outlook. No...read a bit further:

"...these recent developments...have not fundamentally altered our outlook. The economy has been performing well, and we expect it to continue to do so."

And then she mentions that "to be clear":

"...our decision will not hinge on any particular data release or on day-to-day movements in financial markets. Instead, the decision will depend on a wide range of economic and financial indicators and our assessment of their cumulative implications for actual and expected progress toward our objectives."

Then she added:

"The recovery from the Great Recession has advanced sufficiently far, and domestic spending appears sufficiently robust, that an argument can be made for a rise in interest rates at this time. We discussed this possibility at our meeting."

Ok. Now it is clear !! The US economy is so close to a rise in interest rates that the Committee has decided to send a very dovish message...go figure.

To be fair, Yellen mentioned that the "Committee judged appropriate to wait for more evidence...to bolster its confidence that inflation will rise to 2 percent".

It seems, thus, that despite the dovish message, the FOMC just wants to wait a bit more to make sure the recent bout of volatility will indeed only have temporary effects on the economy.

That might be the case...but it wasn't the message that came across from the statement, from Yellen's prepared remarks and from the Q&A.
The emphasis on (previously disregarded) market-based inflation compensation, explicit concerns about Chinese growth, the impact of commodity prices on emerging market economies, the capital flight from EM, and even concerns about Canada "which is an important trading partner", all departed from the message conveyed in a similar bout of uncertainty earlier this year and sounded very dovish.

Indeed, from late 2014 to earlier this year, the Fed watched a sell-off in EM currencies, a decline in oil and other commodity prices, a strengthening of the US dollar, a sharp drop in market-based measures of inflation compensation, a sharp slowdown in global trade, West Coast port slowdown, a contraction in first quarter GDP growth,..., and the message conveyed back then was more upbeat.

One thing that stood out was Yellen's remarks on inflation compensation:

"...the Committee has taken note of the recent declines in market-based measures of inflation compensation and will continue to monitor inflation developments carefully."

This was a complete departure from the line of thought of late 2014 and earlier this year!
Back then the FOMC decided to focus on survey-based measures of inflation expectations and disregarded market-based measures of inflation compensation. In February Semiannual Monetary Policy Report to Congress Yellen mentioned that inflation compensation "mainly reflects factors other than a reduction of longer-term inflation expectations". Fed staff even prepared a box in the Monetary Policy Report explaining the "challenges in interpreting measures of longer-term inflation expectations" from financial instruments.

To be fair, when speaking by herself (and not on behalf of the Committee), Yellen often seemed more concerned about inflation compensation than the full FOMC.

Allow me a digression to show how inflation extracted from the TIPS for the 5 year period from 2020 to 2025 is correlated with today's oil prices!!
(And, by the way, market-based measures of inflation compensation today are not far away from where they were back in February 2015 when Yellen spoke to the Congress.)

Returning to the main point, it is clear that the FOMC is worried about inflation and that something has changed.
One can clearly see that in their forecasts!!


Don't you think a tenth down change in median forecast and in the central tendency range for inflation reflect a material change? Well, you've got company. It is very hard to argue that a tenth move is not well within any forecast error margin...

But, what about the move in headline PCE down from 0.7% to 0.4%? Well, that's really a large shift, but note that the core PCE rose from 1.3% to 1.4%. Moreover, would the FOMC make today's monetary policy based on the forecast for the next 3 months? Even Yellen believes monetary policy has lags..."But there are lags in the impact of monetary policy on the economy" she answered in the Q&A.

So, if the FOMC has not materially changed the forecasts, has the dovish message resulted from a change in the balance of risks? The statement reads:

"The Committee continues to see the risks to the outlook for economic activity and labor market as nearly balanced but is monitoring developments abroad."

It seems the risks remain balanced but worth monitoring; so has uncertainty increased?
Yellen mentioned in the prepared remarks that "the outlook abroad appears to have become more uncertain of late, and heightened concerns about growth in China and other emerging market economies have led to notable volatility in financial markets".

So it seems that an increase in uncertainty was behind the change to a more dovish stance. But what is odd is that this uncertainty is not reflected in the forecasts. Look at GDP, unemployment and inflation forecast in the table above: forecast ranges have not changed materially from June -- this does not reflect an increase in uncertainty (or the Fed was not brave enough to change forecasts and acknowledge the worsening of the outlook and increased uncertainty).

So, the Fed has not materially changed the outlook, neither the balance of risks, but has acknowledged an increase in uncertainty. And if one is not willing to show this uncertainty in the forecasts, you show it by lowering the 'dots' when your forecasts suggest otherwise, and sounding dovish.


Would the markets really get surprised with a liftoff?

Posted on September 16th, 2015

  • No.
  • Fed fund futures imply less of 30% change of the first hike on Sept. 17.
  • Surveys (e.g., Bloomberg, FT) suggest the odds are closer to 50/50.
  • More interestingly, the term structure of the yield curve already has one hike fully priced!!


One of the key arguments against an increase in fed funds on September 17th is the fact that the Fed has not provided a 'heads-up' and therefore the market is not prepared for it. It would be too disruptive to move away from the ZLB without the markets being prepared for it, the argument goes.

So, would markets really get surprised in the event of a liftoff?

The immediate answer is yes -- just look at the fed fund futures and you'll see that the probability of leaving the zero bound is as low as 30%. The Fed only moved in the last 20 years when the implied probability is north of 70%, Larry Summers recently said.

But looking at economist surveys, one gets a different picture. A Bloomberg survey shows that 51 out of 113 economists / strategists expect the Fed to move 25bp on Sept. 17th and 3 expect a move half this size. A similar survey by the FT shows 47% of 30 economists expect a move.

One may quickly dismiss surveys and argue that market prices provide a more accurate picture.

So, let's take a closer look at market prices other than Fed funds futures.
The term structure of the yield curve provides valuable information. From 1985 to 2007, 99% of the variance of the term structure of the yield curve can be explained by two factors (the first 2 PCA).

The chart below shows that using the common information provided in the 6m, 1y, 2y, 3y, 5y, 7y, 10y, 20y, and 30y constant maturity treasuries one can closely replicate the actual Fed funds rate. Note that the PCA calculated does not include the FF.


So it is clear that the term structure contains information on the fed funds rate. Note also how the blue line (FF compatible with the term structure) often (but not always) anticipates the move in the actual fed funds.

What if we use the model coefficients estimated up to 2007 (to avoid including the period of the crisis) to forecast where the fed funds rate should have settled, based only on the actual path of the yield curve term structure? (again, not using the actual fed funds).

The chart below shows that the estimated fed funds would have been negative for most of the ZLB period. Except for the last few months!

Zooming into the ZLB period, one can see that the term structure of the yield curve is compatible with a fed funds rate which has increased since Jan/2014 and matched the actual fed funds by November 2014.
The most recent data shows that the term structure is compatible with fed funds at about 35bp, exactly where the market expects the FF to trade after the first hike!


Bottom line: the term structure of the yield curve already embeds one hike.


Will they or won't they -- headwinds for the FOMC

Posted on September 16th, 2015

  • The overall economic data released since Fed's latest meeting suggests the criteria for liftoff has been met.
  • However, headwinds from the recent developments abroad and tightening of financial conditions in the US will likely postpone the first hike.
  • The Fed has not elaborated upon the way it sees the balance of risks -- so we're flying blind.
  • The key rational for believing a hike will be delayed is that the Fed has not provided any 'heads-up'.
  • Charts below: dollar, commodities, financial conditions.

Charts


US trade-weighted dollar is higher than earlier in the year, when Fed warned about its negative consequences to the economy

Oil prices are also back to the lows of earlier this year

Retail gasoline prices are not at the lows but have trended down since July

Commodity prices have just made new lows


US equities are 7% down since mid August

Equity vol off the highs but still elevated

US 10y Treasuries

Baa spreads widened materially vs Aaa

Market-based inflation compensation sharply down, but this could just be oil prices

Financial conditions, as measured by GS, have already tightened sharply in 2015...

...but broadening the definition to include oil prices show a more benign picture

Financial conditions, as measured by the Chicago Fed, also show a tightening, but overall levels remain in the accommodative range

Adjusting for the business cycle, Chicago Fed index suggest that financial conditions moved to tight since the beginning of 2015

Below, some additional financial conditions and financial stress indices




Paulo Gustavo Grahl, CFA

Random comments on macro data. Views are my own. Except when they aren't.